Intended for healthcare professionals

Editorials

China's one child policy

BMJ 2006; 333 doi: https://doi.org/10.1136/bmj.38938.412593.80 (Published 17 August 2006) Cite this as: BMJ 2006;333:361
  1. Malcolm Potts, Fred H Bixby endowed chair (potts{at}berkeley.edu)
  1. School of Public Health, University of California, Berkeley, CA 94720-7360, USA

    The policy that changed the world

    The Chinese one child policy is unique in the history of the world. It was a source of great pain for one generation, but a generation later it began to yield important economic benefits. For China, and the world as a whole, the one child policy was one of the most important social policies ever implemented.

    Rapid population growth is an unforgiving task master. Even with the one child policy—as a result of the high birth rate a generation before—China still has one million more births than deaths every five weeks. The Chinese State Council launched the policy in 1979, “so the rate of population growth may be brought under control as soon as possible.” However, the root cause of the policy lay back in the 1960s with Mao Zedong's belief that “the more people, the stronger we are”—an ideology that prevented China from developing the highly successful voluntary family planning programmes that countries such as South Korea and Taiwan had put in place in the 1960s.1

    Deng Xiao-ping, the acknowledged architect of China's contemporary economic miracle, was a major sponsor of the 1979 policy. He said that unless the birth rate fell rapidly, “we will not be able to develop our economy, and raise the living standards of our people.”2 Economists and demographers now recognise that a falling birth rate offers a demographic dividend, as the economically productive proportion of the population grows more rapidly than the general population.3 4 Without a rapid decline in fertility, China's economy would not have grown by 7-8% a year over the past decade; such growth has lifted an unprecedented 150 million people out of abject poverty.

    Could China ever have achieved the same results without the one child policy? Possibly. Between 1952 and 1979, the Chinese total fertility rate fell from 6.5 to 2.75, and today all age groups and social classes prefer to have two children or fewer.5 Some western commentators believe China over-reacted,6 whereas others emphasise that even small changes in the timing of a decline in fertility are important. The difference between a total fertility rate of 2.1, which might have been achieved without the policy, and a total fertility rate of 1.6 (found today) releases 24% more resources for the family and national investment. The Indian economy has begun to grow rapidly, but unlike China the decline in fertility has been uneven, and states such as Bihar and Uttar Pradesh (total fertility rates of 4.4 and 4.8) remain mired in poverty.

    As well as its effect on fertility rates, China's one child policy has had a variety of other effects. Each successive birth cohort is smaller and women tend to marry men who are several years older than themselves, so fewer potential brides are available than grooms. Further, like many countries, China has a long tradition of favouring boys and the technology of ultrasound and selective abortion, although illegal, has further skewed the sex ratio. The under-registration of female births and higher mortality due to greater neglect of female babies makes exact measurement difficult, but Ding and Hesketh found a ratio of male to female births of 1.15 across the whole cohort and of 1.23 for first births between 1996 and 2001.5 Lastly, when birth rates fall rapidly, during their most productive years the younger generation needs to support a high ratio of old people,7 although as people age they may also save at a higher rate.8 China's new prosperity has repercussions around the world in other ways—for instance, Chinese competition for oil is one reason that the cost of petrol is so high.

    Undoubtedly, the one child policy caused great individual pain and it has been heavily criticised. For people in the United States especially, the idea that society's long term interests could ever be more important than individual rights was anathema. A veritable media industry has arisen in the US criticising the one child policy, although it chooses to overlook the tens of millions of coercive pregnancies in other countries where family planning and legal abortion are not available. The Bush administration refuses to fund the United Nations Population Fund because it works in China, even though this fund has never supported the one child policy.

    The Chinese demographic crisis arose because between 1960 and 1973 the population grew by 2% or more each year. Today, the whole of sub-Saharan Africa, along with Pakistan, Iraq, Afghanistan, and the Philippines, have population growth rates of at least 2%. Between now and 2050 the population of Niger, West Africa, is projected to grow fivefold from 14 to 53 million. As the World Bank acknowledges,9 without a rapid decline in fertility, tens of millions of Nigeriens will be uneducated, unemployed, and desperately poor; they will either starve or be fed by Western humanitarian aid.

    Last month, the UK All Party Parliamentary Group on Population, Development, and Reproductive Health ended an important series of hearings on the impact of population growth on the millennium development goals. Experts from around the world called on the UK's Department for International Development and the international community to give much greater emphasis to population and family planning. Baige Zhao, vice minister of the National Population and Family Planning Commission of China offered “to share our information and also our commodities.”10 As China reaches out to help other countries, their contribution to international family planning could prove an important additional global benefit of the sacrifices the Chinese people made to implement the one child policy.

    Footnotes

    • Competing interests None declared.

    • Research p 371

    References

    1. 1.
    2. 2.
    3. 3.
    4. 4.
    5. 5.
    6. 6.
    7. 7.
    8. 8.
    9. 9.
    10. 10.
    View Abstract

    Log in

    Log in through your institution

    Subscribe

    * For online subscription